AFIN8003 Week 1 - Introduction

Banking and Financial Intermediation

Dr. Mingze Gao

Department of Applied Finance

2024-07-24

Course admin

Teaching staff

  • Unit convener: Dr. Mingze Gao.
  • Lecturer in Finance, MQBS.
  • PhD in Finance (USyd), Grad.Cert. in Computing (UNSW), BCom (Hon) in Finance (USyd), BCom in Econometrics and Finance (USyd).
  • Postdoctoral Research Fellow (USyd), 2021-2023.
  • Research in banking and corporate finance.

Contact:

About this course

Course description:

  • This unit applies finance theory to the context of operational decision-making and risk management in banking and financial intermediation.
  • The major decision areas for banking management are covered within a regulatory and corporate responsibility framework.
  • Major risks of banks and financial intermediation are being examined.

Key approaches:

  • Research-informed teaching.
  • Australian focus with global evidence.
  • Priority on bank risk management.

Course materials

The course materials are prepared based on several sources. Additional references are provided at the end of each week’s slides.

  • Saunders, Cornett, and Erhemjamts (2023)
  • Freixas and Rochet (2023)

Weekly topics

  1. Introduction to banking and financial intermediation
  2. Risks and regulation
  3. Capital management and adequacy
  4. Interest rate risk
  5. Market risk
  6. Credit risk I: individual loan risk
  7. Midterm exam
  8. Credit risk II: loan portfolio and concentration risk
  9. Liquidity risk
  10. Liability and liquidity management
  11. Sovereign risk, foreign exchange risk, and off-balance-sheet risk
  12. Loan sales and securitisation
  13. Emerging topics in bank risk management

Assessments

There are three assessments in this course.

Assessment Weight Hurdle When
Midterm exam 20% No Week 7
Individual assignment 30% No Due in Week 12
Final exam 50% No University Examination Period

Background

Financial system

A financial system encompasses various financial intermediaries, markets, regulators, and infrastructure in the generation and distribution of financial resources.

A well developed smoothly functioning facilitates the efficient life-cycle allocation of household consumption and the efficient allocation of physical capital to its most productive use in the business sector (Merton 1993).

Robert Merton, Nobel laureate (1997)

Financial intermediation

Financial intermediation is part of the financial system.

  • It is the process by which financial intermediaries, such as banks, facilitate the flow of funds between savers and borrowers.
  • Banks are a major part of financial intermediation.
    • Banks were essentially the only provider of financial intermediation.
    • Since 1970s, dramatic development development of the financial market:
      • Other intermediaries performing similar functions of banks.
      • FinTech, bigtech in money and credit services.
      • Cryptocurrencies, central bank digital currencies.

Why is banking and financial intermediation necessary?

A historical perspective:

  • Finance is critical in real economic activities.
    • Excessive debt levels and liquidity constraints could lead to downward spirals in economic activity, as witnessed during the Great Depression (Fisher 1933)1
  • “Finance is a veil”, late 50s to early 70s.
    • In a frictionless market, firm value is not affected by its capital structure so that financial intermediaries can be redundant (Modigliani and Miller 1958).
  • Finance is relevant, since 70s.
    • Market frictions amplify economic cycles, particularly during downturns. Monetary factors alone are insufficient to explain the Great Depression’s depth and persistence - it’s more because of the collapse of the bank credit (Bernanke 1983, the “financial accelerator”).

Why is banking and financial intermediation necessary?

A banking analogue of the Modigliani and Miller (1958) theorem showing that banks are useless with perfect financial markets.

  • An economy of firms, households, banks and a bond market.
    • Households consume, and lend through banks or through the bond market.
    • Firms produce, and borrow from banks or from households through the bond market.
    • Banks borrow from households and lend to firms.

In a competitive equilibrium, banks make zero profit and have no impact on other agents’ decisions. Firms are indifferent between bank credit and bonds.

  • Banks and bond market are perfect substitutes in a market without frictions.

Why is banking and financial intermediation necessary?

The existence of banks (and other financial intermediaries) must be justified by their roles in mitigating market frictions.

  • Information asymmetry.

From an industrial organization perspective, the structure and competition of banking sector should have a unique impact on the economy, which warrants for regulation.

  • The services provided by banks to borrowers and savers must be costly.
    • Monitoring costs.
    • Liquidity costs.

Empirical evidence

Figure 1: The share of financial sector of economic output is relatively stable

The specialness of bank and financial intermediaries

Importance of banks and financial intermediaries

We start this banking course by studying the importance of banks in improving the efficient allocation of financial resources in the economy.

  • Specifically, why market frictions necessitate banks.
  • A simple look at the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model.

An economy without financial intermediaries

The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model

Figure 2: A simple diagram of an economy without financial intermediaries

Some frictions render this setup unappealing.

  • Households are uncertain about when they will need their money. They might need it either in the short term or in the long term.
  • Firms need long-term capital in production.
  • Banks1 are best positioned to perform maturity transformation.

Model setup

The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model

Let’s see a simplified Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model:1

  • Three dates, \(t=0,1,2.\)
  • Each household has initial goods of 1 unit at \(t=0\).
    • They can invest long-term to earn \(R>1\) at \(t=2\) for consumption, or
    • store it for consumption at \(t=1\) or \(t=2\), which remains 1 unit.
    • If they choose to liquidate the long-term investment at \(t=1\), they get \(l<1\) (costly liquidation).
  • Household do not know whether they need to consume early at \(t=1\).
    • A sudden need for money, e.g., medical bills (note there that we do not introduce insurance - but banks can provide such liquidity insurance).
    • Key assumption.

Model implications

The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model

Not bothered by math, the implications are:

  • We can determine the theoretical optimal allocation.
  • Without transactions between agents, the allocation is inefficient.
  • With transactions (financial market/bond market), the allocation is still not efficient.
    • Consumption can be transferred between \(t=1\) and \(t=2\).
    • Liquidation costs avoided.
  • The optimal allocation can be achieved with competitive banks offering deposit contracts and investing in the long-term.
    • A bank simultaneously take deposits from the public and grant loans to borrowers.
    • Transform short-term deposits to long-term assets.

Maturity transformation by bank

The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model

Figure 3: A simple diagram of bank’s maturity transformation

  • This structure, however, gives rise to bank runs where everyone withdraws at \(t=1\).
    • The Silicon Valley Bank (SVB) failure in March 2023 is a typical bank run.
  • No other risks considered.

Beyond maturity transformation

Asset transformation, risk transformation and liquidity transformation.

  • Banks make investments in borrowers - primary claims - illiquid and risky.
  • Savers deposit in banks - secondary claims - liquid and low risk.

Information frictions

Banks do more than maturity transformation.

Banks are also better positioned to mitigate informational frictions in the market due to economies of scale.

  • The cost advantages by spreading the costs over a large number of customers, transactions, and output.
  • The costs arise from all aspects of lending process: screening, monitoring, and auditing; all of which can be costly for individual household lenders.

Information asymmetry and costs

  • Screening costs in the context of adverse selection (Broecker 1990).
    • Borrower knows better about its quality than lenders.
    • Occurs before a loan is made.
  • Monitoring costs in the context of moral hazard (Holmstrom and Tirole 1997).
    • Borrower could engage in opportunistic behaviour with private benefits at the cost of lenders.
    • Occurs after a loan is made.
  • Auditing costs in the context of borrower failing to meet contractual obligations.
    • Renegotiate loan terms, recover loan value, etc.
    • Occurs in case of non-compliance.

Banks as delegated monitor

Diamond (1984) model, overly simplified:

  • \(n\) large borrowers, each requires \(1\) unit of funds and costs \(K\) to monitor, and
  • \(nm\) small savers each with \(1/m\) units of funds (\(m>1\)); a total of \(n\) units of funds.
  • Total monitoring costs is \(nmK\) if savers individually monitor, but
  • \(mK\) if the bank acts as the monitor on behalf of savers.

Figure 4: A simple diagram of bank as delegated monitor

Banks as delegated monitor

Economies of scale is evident:

  • Total monitoring costs reduced from \(nmK\) to \(mK\).
  • Delegated monitoring reduces unnecessary duplication of monitoring costs.
  • The more savers, the lower the cost per saver.

A caveat. It must be that the cost of delegation is smaller than the benefits gained from economies of scale. The delegated monitor needs to be monitored, too.

  • Requirement is that the bank needs to be sufficiently diversified (Diamond 1984).

The Holmstrom and Tirole (1997) model

Key insights:

  • Firms with profitable projects will still be credit rationed if they do not have sufficient internal capital - they will not be able to raise capital from the market.
  • Banks can alleviate this problem by providing credit to firms and monitoring borrowers.
  • Banks improve the market.

Changing dynamics

FinTech, bigtech, and more

  • Traditional “banks”, taking deposits and grant loans, are facing increasing challenges.
  • Global competition with other banks.
  • Competition with nonbanks or “shadow banks”.
    • Many of banks’ functions can be now performed by nonbanks.
    • For example, FinTech firms may better reduce information asymmetry through screening and monitoring based on big data and advanced technologies (AI/ML), improved and customized services, and reduced cost of search and match with platform economy.
    • More importantly, nonbanks are not regulated or less regulated than banks.
  • Central bank digital currencies (CBDC).
    • Increased funding costs for banks if households hold CBDC instead of bank deposits.
  • Technological advancement.
    • Online/mobile banking simplifies transfer of funds.
  • Transition from “originate and hold” to “originate and distribute” business model.

The financial services industry

Types of financial institutions

The Australian’s central bank, Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA), classifies financial institutions into broadly three categories:1

  1. Authorised depository-taking institutions (ADI)
  2. Non-ADI financial institutions
  3. Insurers and fund managers

Authorised depository-taking institutions (ADI)

Financial institutions authorised by the Australia Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) to carry out financial intermediation are called authorised depository institutions (ADIs).

  • These depository-taking institutions (DIs) are the focus of this course.
  • Three DI groups in Australia: banks, building societies and credit unions.
Table 1: Typical balance sheet of a DI
Assets Liabilities and Equity
Loans Deposits
Other assets Other liabilities
Equity

Banks

Depositary-taking institutions (DI)

  • Banks are the largest depository institutions in terms of size.
  • Major difference between banks and credit unions/savings institutions: banks have more varied assets and liabilities.
  • Differences in operating characteristics and profitability across size classes - for instance, with regards to the size of the commercial loan portfolio.

Largest banks globally

Largest banks by total assets in 2024, according to S&P Global Market Intelligence:

Rank Company Headquarter Total assets ($B)
1 Industrial and Commercial Bank of China Ltd. China 6,303.44
2 Agricultural Bank of China Ltd. China 5,623.12
3 China Construction Bank Corp. China 5,400.28
4 Bank of China Ltd. China 4,578.28
5 JPMorgan Chase & Co. US 3,875.39
6 Bank of America Corp. US 3,180.15
7 HSBC Holdings PLC UK 2,919.84
8 BNP Paribas SA France 2,867.44
9 Mitsubishi UFJ Financial Group Inc. Japan 2,816.77
10 Crédit Agricole Group France 2,736.95
42 Commonwealth Bank of Australia Australia 868.74

Banks in Australia

Four major banks: CBA, ANZ, NAB, and Westpac.

  • national focus, “four pillars policy”
  • offer corporate and retail banking services in Australia, NZ and Papua New Guinea
  • they also operate in Asia, the US and the UK
  • focus on lending (around 70 per cent).

Other major banks: Macquarie Bank, Bendigo and Adelaide Bank, Bank of Queensland, Suncorp, AMP Bank, etc.

Regional banks

  • regional focus with operations across state borders
  • large proportion of assets invested in residential housing loans due to their origins as building societies
  • focus on lending

Banks in Australia: funding composition

Figure 5: Funding composition of banks in Australia

Banks in Australia: net interest margin

Figure 6: NIM of banks in Australia

Banks in Australia: non-performing assets

Figure 7: Non-performing assets of banks in Australia

Credit unions and building societies

Depositary-taking institutions (DI)

Credit Unions

  • Mutual cooperative organisations that provide deposit facilities, personal and housing loans and payments services to their members, who are usually linked by way of some common bond
  • Primarily provide deposit facilities, personal and housing loans and payments services
  • Members are usually linked by a common bond, such as a trade union or locality
  • In 2014 there were 84 credit unions in Australia, compared to 348 in 1992

Building Societies

  • DIs that traditionally were mutually owned, but are increasingly issuing share capital
  • Depositors are members of the society
  • In 2014 there were 9 building societies, compared to 31 in 1992

Both credit unions and building societies are subject to the same prudential regulations as banks.

Only 36 credit unions and building societies in 2023.

Non-ADI financial institutions

  • Money market corporations (broker-dealers)
    • Primarily wholesale credit market.
    • Investing, investment banking, market making, trading.
  • Finance companies
    • Loans to households and SMEs.
    • Funding from debentures and unsecured notes.
  • Securitisers
    • Special-purpose vehicles (SPVs) that issue securities backed by pools of assets (e.g. residential mortgage-backed securities).

Insurers and fund managers

  • Insurance companies
    • Life insurers: provide life, accident and disability insurance, annuities, investment and superannuation products.
    • General insurers: provide insurance for property, motor vehicles, employers’ liability, etc.
    • Health insurers: provide insurance for private health costs.
      • Medibank, Bupa, HCF, etc.
  • Superannuation and approved deposit funds
  • Public unit trusts
  • Cash management trusts
  • Common funds
  • Friendly societies

Life insurers in Australia

Top 10 life insurers by total assets in 2023:

Company Total Assets Share
Resolution Life Australasia Limited (former AMP) 25,636,094,000 21.11%
Challenger Life Company Limited 25,025,565,000 20.61%
AIA Australia Limited 14,999,640,516 12.35%
TAL Life Limited 12,451,370,000 10.25%
Zurich Australia Limited 8,268,873,000 6.81%
MLC Limited 6,775,456,183 5.58%
Munich Reinsurance Company of Australasia Limited 5,401,974,315 4.45%
Swiss Re Life & Health Australia Limited 3,454,823,000 2.85%
TAL Life Insurance Services Limited 3,200,477,631 2.64%
Hannover Life Re of Australasia Ltd 3,053,576,000 2.51%

Superannuation funds

Australian governments have encouraged national savings over last decades through:

  • taxation incentives,
  • legislative requirements, and
  • award superannuation.

Sector represents 30% of the assets of all FIs as at December 2021.

Managed by:

  • specialist superannuation fund managers, e.g., UniSuper
  • self-managed superannuation funds (SMSF)

Non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs)

Non-bank FIs’ assets

Finally…

Suggested readings

References

Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.” The American Economic Review 73 (3): 257–76.
Broecker, Thorsten. 1990. “Credit-Worthiness Tests and Interbank Competition.” Econometrica 58 (2): 429.
Diamond, Douglas W. 1984. “Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring.” The Review of Economic Studies 51 (3): 393–414.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig. 1983. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy 91 (3): 401–19.
Fisher, Irving. 1933. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions.” Econometrica 1 (4): 337.
Freixas, Xavier, and Jean-Charles Rochet. 2023. Microeconomics of Banking. 3rd ed. MIT Press.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Jean Tirole. 1997. “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (3): 663–91.
Merton, R C. 1993. Operation and Regulation in Financial Intermediation: A Functional Perspective. Edited by P Englund. Stockholm: Economic Council.
Modigliani, F, and M H Miller. 1958. “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment.” The American Economic Review 48 (3): 261–97.
Saunders, Anthony, Marcia Millon Cornett, and Otgo Erhemjamts. 2023. Financial Institutions Management ISE. 11th ed. McGraw Hill.